Explore absolute and conditional convergence, the club convergence concept, and how these theories shape long-term economic growth and investment decisions.
Well, let me just confess upfront: when I first encountered the concept of convergence in macroeconomics, I had a bit of a “wait, what exactly are we converging to?” moment. After all, countries are super diverse—some are young economies with limited infrastructure but high growth potential; others boast well-established institutions yet grow at a snail’s pace. Despite these differences, certain economic growth theories say that under the right conditions, all economies (or at least groups of them) may eventually settle at similar per capita income levels. This is what we call “convergence.”
In practice, we delve deeper by distinguishing between absolute convergence (sometimes called unconditional convergence) and conditional convergence, with an extra nuance known as club convergence. Let’s walk through them step by step. I promise it’s not as daunting as it might sound at first glance, and it can have big-time implications for your valuation models and asset allocation strategy—especially if you’re toggling between investing in advanced economies and emerging frontier markets.
Absolute convergence states that poorer economies tend to grow faster than rich ones—eventually “catching up” in terms of per capita income. The classic reasoning behind this is diminishing returns to capital. Economies with huge capital stocks—think advanced economies with cutting-edge infrastructure—may only see modest gains for each additional unit of capital invested. Meanwhile, a developing country with insufficient roads, limited machinery, and low human capital can experience large leaps in productivity per new piece of capital or technology. It’s as if every fresh injection of investment hits the ground running in a less-developed economy.
The concept is often illustrated by the neoclassical growth model (Solow–Swan). In that model, each unit of new capital in a capital-poor country yields higher marginal returns compared to capital-abundant countries. Over time, less-developed nations grow at a faster clip, and their income levels approach those of the richer nations. If you assume identical savings rates, population growth rates, and technology diffusion across all countries, they should, in theory, converge to a common steady-state income level.
Imagine a scenario where advanced economy A has $100,000 GDP per capita, and emerging economy B starts at just $5,000. Suppose economy B invests heavily in roads, factories, and education. Because it’s starting from such a low base, each dollar of investment yields a bigger percentage boost to productivity. Over time, B’s growth rate outstrips A’s. If “nothing else” is different—no bizarre policy differences, no political unrest, and technology can flow freely—proponents of absolute convergence would say that B’s per capita income eventually meets or at least closes in on A’s.
But hold on—does that happen in reality? Not always. Conditional convergence says we need a better look at each country’s “structural characteristics,” such as savings rates, population growth, tax policies, educational infrastructure, and, very importantly, the quality of institutions. If these structural factors aren’t in a similar ballpark, the magic of rapid catch-up growth might remain elusive.
Think about the importance of strong governance, rule of law, and investor protections. Let’s say you’re evaluating a major infrastructure investment in a developing country with high potential returns, but you discover that the legal system is inefficient or property rights are questionable. That might dampen foreign direct investment, technology transfers, or local entrepreneurship. In the end, the theoretical growth spurt you’d expect from a capital-poor, high-return environment might fizzle out.
In many conditional convergence models, the growth path of a country depends on structural variables. Formally, you might see a regression with per capita GDP growth as the dependent variable, and it includes not just initial per capita GDP but also a host of explanatory variables (e.g., education levels, institutional quality, regulatory environment). A negative coefficient on the initial GDP term indicates there’s a conditional catch-up effect, but it’s “conditional” on the other factors the country must share to converge with higher-income nations.
Now, let’s take it one step further: club convergence. This idea suggests that countries don’t all converge to a single universal income level. Instead, they form “clubs.” Each club is made up of countries that have similar initial conditions or institutional frameworks—like strong property rights, stable governments, or well-developed financial systems. Within a club, you might see a subset of countries converging to the same steady-state. But countries in a lower-club equilibrium can remain stuck if they can’t cross the threshold of institutional quality or capital that’s needed to join the higher club.
It may sound a bit like being in a clique in high school—once you’re in the “elite” club, you stay on track to converge within it, but you don’t necessarily mix with the other clubs. “Club membership” often depends on policies, education, or even historical factors that gave certain countries a head start. That’s why we see certain middle-income countries that gravitate toward developed status while others stagnate.
An oft-cited example of near-textbook convergence is the case of the “East Asian Tigers”—Hong Kong SAR, Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan. These economies pursued robust export-led growth, high savings and investment rates, and heavy investment in education and technology. Their per capita GDP soared from relatively modest levels to, in some cases, near or even surpassing that of major Western economies. This phenomenon fits well with the idea of conditional convergence (and arguably club convergence), as these Asian economies intentionally put in place the policies and institutions conducive to growth.
Contrast that with many Sub-Saharan African countries struggling to achieve sustained higher growth. Lack of infrastructure, inadequate governance, and underdeveloped capital markets hamper their ability to leverage new capital in a big productivity-boosting way. As a result, despite potentially high marginal returns to capital, they often fail to attract the necessary investment—domestic or foreign—to jump-start absolute convergence. This is a classic example of how institutional solidity underpins growth trajectories.
One big takeaway? If an economy seeks to catch up, it can’t just invest in factories and roads. It’s got to improve legal frameworks, reduce corruption, elevate education standards, and maintain sound monetary and fiscal policies. For emerging market investors or analysts, paying attention to these conditions might guide long-term asset allocation. After all, a high official GDP growth forecast doesn’t mean much if the structural factors are stacked against actual “convergence-level” success.
Two important empirical measures help us track the presence (or absence) of convergence:
• Beta-convergence (β-convergence)
• Sigma-convergence (σ-convergence)
Beta-convergence focuses on whether poorer economies (or regions within a country) are growing faster than richer ones. If the coefficient on initial per capita GDP is negative and statistically significant in a growth regression, we label that “beta-convergence.” Your typical regression might look like this in a panel of countries (over some time frame t to t+n):
• \( Y_{i,t} \) is per capita GDP in period t.
• \( X_{i,t} \) represents other control variables, like savings, institutional quality, or population growth.
• If \(\beta < 0\), then a lower \( Y_{i,t} \) (poorer economy) is associated with higher subsequent growth, consistent with convergence.
Sigma-convergence is about the dispersion or spread of income levels across economies. If the standard deviation (or variance) in GDP per capita across countries declines over time—i.e., they’re getting closer together—then we have sigma-convergence.
What’s interesting is you might see beta-convergence but not sigma-convergence. That is, some countries might be growing faster than rich ones (pointing to a negative β value), but the overall spread of incomes isn’t necessarily shrinking if some countries lag drastically. The interplay of these two measures provides a more complete story about whether we’re witnessing true catch-up growth across the board.
Below is a simple Mermaid diagram to illustrate different paths of convergence:
graph LR A["Lower-Income Country <br/> (High Potential Growth)"] --> B["Higher Growth Rate"] B --> C["Rising Income Levels"] C --> D["Possible Convergence <br/> If Structural Conditions Are Met"] D --> E["Stable Club or Steady-State"]
In an absolute sense, we assume A’s economy can quickly accumulate capital for greater returns. In a conditional sense, the arrow from C to D is contingent on “If Structural Conditions Are Met.” If not, the economy might stall before real convergence is reached.
Learning about convergence helps in multi-country asset allocation decisions. Perhaps your client wants exposure to emerging markets for higher potential returns. As a CFA candidate, you’ll want the conceptual foundation to ask: “Are we looking at a real catch-up candidate with strong institutions or a country stuck in the low-income trap?” The answer might shape your approach to risk premiums and discount rates.
Moreover, from a currency perspective, if an emerging economy is converging quickly, you can expect stronger fundamentals, potentially more stable exchange rates, or even revaluation of the currency over time. This can drastically alter your portfolio returns. On the flip side, a stagnating economy—despite being capital-poor—might see persistent currency or political risk that undermines returns.
• Don’t assume all low-income countries will automatically converge. Keep an eye on governance, geopolitical stability, and education levels.
• Look at both beta and sigma convergence—some countries might show fast growth relative to rich economies (beta), but global disparities remain wide (lack of sigma).
• Remember club convergence: an economy might run into “club boundaries” if it doesn’t adopt best-in-class policies or institutions.
• Don’t ignore the possibility of short-term disruptions. Convergence is typically a long-run concept, so cyclical downturns or commodity shocks can muddy short-run data.
• Barro, R.J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1992). “Convergence.” The Journal of Political Economy.
• World Economic Forum (Institutional Quality & Growth Studies):
https://www.weforum.org
• CFA Institute curriculum on global macroeconomic growth.
Convergence sounds straightforward—poorer economies catching up to richer ones—but the details are more nuanced and, yes, somewhat messy in reality. Absolute convergence posits catch-up no matter what, while conditional convergence says, “Well, only if you share similar structural traits.” Club convergence points out that countries may stratify into distinct groups, each forging its own steady-state path. For those of us in the investment world, recognizing which scenario is unfolding can significantly shape our expectations about long-term returns, asset prices, and currency moves.
And maybe, from a personal vantage point, it’s a reminder that context is everything. If someone brings me a bright new emerging market story that projects 8% annual growth straight into infinity, I might gently nod and say, “Ah, but what are the institutions like? How’s the government? The rule of law? How stable is that capital structure?” Because if those improvements aren’t on track, that 8% might remain just a hope rather than a reality.
Important Notice: FinancialAnalystGuide.com provides supplemental CFA study materials, including mock exams, sample exam questions, and other practice resources to aid your exam preparation. These resources are not affiliated with or endorsed by the CFA Institute. CFA® and Chartered Financial Analyst® are registered trademarks owned exclusively by CFA Institute. Our content is independent, and we do not guarantee exam success. CFA Institute does not endorse, promote, or warrant the accuracy or quality of our products.