Explore foundational yield curve theories, including Pure Expectations and Liquidity Preference, and learn how they inform interest rate projections, investment decision-making, and credit analysis.
Yield curves are like a window into the market’s collective interest rate outlook. They offer insight into everything from short-term monetary policy expectations to long-run economic growth prospects. In other words, if you want to get a feel for where rates might be headed, analyzing the yield curve is a great place to start.
But where does its shape even come from? You’ll often hear that short-term interest rates are shooting upward or that the curve is flattening as a harbinger of a recession. Various theories attempt to answer the big question: Why do we see particular yield curve shapes at different times? In this section, we’ll explore the main yield curve theories:
• Pure (Unbiased) Expectations Theory
• Liquidity Preference Theory
• Market Segmentation (Preferred Habitat) Theory
We’ll then see how they help us interpret yield curve shifts and what it all means for portfolio management. As we dig in, you might recall times you glanced at interest rates—maybe while researching mortgages or corporate bond issuance—and had trouble explaining why the 30-year yield was higher (or rarely, but sometimes lower!) than the 2-year yield. By the end of this discussion, you’ll feel much more confident interpreting and forecasting those changes.
The Pure (Unbiased) Expectations Theory is the simplest explanation of the yield curve’s shape. It says, “Long-term interest rates are basically the geometric averages of expected short-term rates over the life of the longer bond.” Or in plainer language: the yield curve is a direct reflection of where investors believe short-term rates are headed. It doesn’t assume any extra premium for uncertainty or liquidity. If investors think short-term rates will be higher in the future, the yield curve slopes upward; if they expect falling short-term rates, then the curve could flatten or even invert.
Let’s say we have a two-year zero-coupon bond. According to the Pure Expectations Theory, its yield, denoted as R₂, should be the average of:
• Today’s one-year spot rate (R₁), and
• Next year’s expected one-year rate (E[R₁,1year from now]).
In formal terms:
Which implies:
In more general contexts with longer maturities, the yield on an n-year bond is the geometric mean of all the short-term rates the market expects over those n years.
• Strength: It’s straightforward—no extra bells and whistles. If you want a direct read of future rate expectations, this model is your friend.
• Weakness: In reality, most bondholders do demand something extra for tying up their money longer (especially if they’re uncertain about liquidity or inflation). Pure Expectations Theory doesn’t incorporate that premium.
You might think of it like planning a road trip. The total drive time is an average of each leg’s speed—but real life might require a detour or a coffee stop. That’s where the other theories come in.
The Liquidity Preference Theory proposes that investors demand higher yields for longer maturities because a lot can happen over a prolonged period—economic cycles, changes in monetary policy, unexpected choppiness in markets, or, you know, a global pandemic. Holding a long-maturity bond means tying up your cash for years or decades, exposing you to significant interest rate risk.
Because of this, investors typically want an added “term premium” (also called a liquidity premium) on top of any rate expectations. Even if short-term rates were expected to remain the same, longer-dated bonds would often still yield more due to this extra cushion.
When the liquidity premium is plugged into yield calculations, you naturally get an upward bias to the curve. This often explains why yield curves are normally upward sloping. Granted, you can still get flat or inverted curves if the market expects dramatic drops in future short-term rates. But in many stable economic environments, the liquidity premium is what keeps longer yields above shorter yields.
You can think of this from a personal standpoint: if you let a friend borrow $100 for a week, you might be content earning just a small interest rate. But if you lend that same friend $100 for 10 years—and have to watch inflation, default risks, and a million other life changes—chances are you’ll demand a bigger reward. That’s the liquidity premium at work.
Market Segmentation Theory (often referred to in textbooks as Preferred Habitat Theory) suggests that different groups of investors have unique maturity preferences. There’s a group that only wants super-short maturities to avoid interest rate risk (like money market funds or certain banks). Then there’s pension funds or insurers that prefer long-dated bonds to match their long-term liabilities. Each group essentially stays in its own “corner” of the curve.
Because of these distinct preferences (or habitats), yields at particular maturities are heavily influenced by localized supply and demand. If insurers desperately need 20- or 30-year maturities to match liabilities, they may drive up prices for those bonds, pushing yields lower at that segment. Meanwhile, if there’s high demand for short-term T-bills from corporate treasuries, that segment might see yields decline.
All these mini-markets collectively form the overall yield curve, which can sometimes lead to humps or other shapes not fully explained by a pure expectations or liquidity preference framework.
Pension funds and life insurance companies often have regulatory or economic capital reasons to invest in certain durations. Corporations focusing on near-term liquidity might heavily prefer short-term bonds or commercial paper. Governments might issue more heavily at certain maturities depending on budget constraints. All of these actions create pockets of differing supply and demand along the curve.
Below is a simple diagram comparing key aspects of these theories:
flowchart LR A["Pure Expectations <br/>Theory"] --> B["Long rates = <br/>averages of <br/>future short rates"] C["Liquidity <br/>Preference Theory"] --> D["Investors require <br/>an extra premium <br/>for long maturity"] E["Market Segmentation <br/>Theory"] --> F["Distinct maturity <br/>markets driven by <br/>investor needs"]
• Pure Expectations Theory: Ignores any risk premium; focuses purely on expected short rates.
• Liquidity Preference Theory: Adds a premium to longer maturities for the added risk taken.
• Market Segmentation Theory: Merges the idea of supply and demand in discrete maturity buckets.
Normally, a positively sloped yield curve (i.e., longer maturities with higher yields) can mean the market expects higher future short-term rates (Pure Expectations view) or is demanding a premium for longer maturities (Liquidity Preference view). It also might reflect that investor demand is balanced more toward certain short segments, leaving the longer segments less in demand.
A flattening curve can signal that the market expects short rates to level off or even decline in the future. When things invert—where short rates exceed long rates—some folks see that as a strong recession indicator. Indeed, historical data in multiple markets suggests yield curve inversions often precede downturns. But keep in mind, under the Market Segmentation Theory, an inverted curve might also arise because a group of investors or central banks is drastically shifting its demand in the short end (driving short-bond prices up and yields down) or pulling away from the long end (pushing yields higher)—and that localized effect can overshadow the usual flattening logic.
During certain economic cycles (say, in the run-up to a central bank tightening policy), the short end of the curve might rise sharply, while the long end barely budges because investors think the tightening will control inflation down the road. That can flatten or invert the curve. So, watch out for big supply/demand changes in certain maturity ranges, as that can also drastically shape the curve.
Portfolio managers who anticipate rising short-term rates might allocate more to shorter maturities or reposition using interest rate futures. On the flip side, if they sense rates are plateauing, they might move out on the curve to capture slightly higher yields. Understanding yield curve theories helps managers hypothesize which forces could shift rates in each segment.
Life insurers and pension funds often adopt strategies that lock in a certain yield to match expected liabilities. Market Segmentation Theory is quite relevant for these investors since they operate in a specific “habitat” driven by liability durations. Liquidity Preferences can guide them on how much extra yield they might demand if they shift to slightly different maturities.
In prior chapters (see Chapter 6 on Bond Pricing and Valuation Basics), you learned about discounting bond cash flows by the appropriate spot rates. The yield curve essentially represents a set of spot rates across maturities. If you think the Liquidity Preference Theory is correct, you might expect the discount rate on a 20-year bond to incorporate a higher premium. Under Pure Expectations, your discount rate might be primarily about where short rates are expected to go.
• Unbiased Expectations: The hypothesis that forward rates purely reflect predicted future spot rates, absent any premiums.
• Term Premium (Liquidity Premium): The additional yield that investors demand for assuming the risks of a longer maturity.
• Preferred Habitat: Zones of the yield curve where investors prefer to operate because of their risk tolerance, regulation, or liability structure.
• Convexity Bias: The phenomenon where longer-term bonds might gain relative value under volatile rate expectations, because of the shape of the price-yield relationship.
• Best Practice: Look at forward rate agreements and see how they compare to your internal rate forecasts. If they differ substantially, examine whether liquidity or segmentation factors might explain the discrepancy.
• Common Pitfall: Blindly applying one theory to all markets. Real-world yield curves can be driven by a combination of expectations, liquidity premiums, and segmentation quirks!
• Strategy: Use scenario analysis to stress test multiple yield curve shapes (steep, flat, inverted). Incorporate your assumptions about term premiums and supply/demand pockets.
I vividly remember reviewing yield curve data when central banks started implementing quantitative easing. The usual upward slope you learn about in textbooks got all out of whack—long yields plummeted as central banks soaked up the supply, while short yields were pinned near zero. It was a perfect example of Market Segmentation in action because, effectively, the central bank became a massive buyer (demand) in a specific zone of the curve. The result? Even if you believed short-term rates would stay at 0% for years, you still needed some context to explain why 10-year yields got as low as they did during those times.
If you’d like to dive deeper, consider these references:
• Vayanos, D. & Vila, J.-L. (2009). “A Preferred-Habitat Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates.” NBER.
• Mishkin, F.S. “The Economics of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets.”
• Chapter 7 of your official CFA curriculum (especially earlier sections on constructing yield curves).
• Academic research on term premium decomposition (this can get quite quantitative but is super enlightening).
• Vayanos, D. & Vila, J.-L. (2009). “A Preferred-Habitat Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates.” National Bureau of Economic Research.
• Mishkin, F. S. “The Economics of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets.”
• CFA Institute. “CFA Program Curriculum.”
Important Notice: FinancialAnalystGuide.com provides supplemental CFA study materials, including mock exams, sample exam questions, and other practice resources to aid your exam preparation. These resources are not affiliated with or endorsed by the CFA Institute. CFA® and Chartered Financial Analyst® are registered trademarks owned exclusively by CFA Institute. Our content is independent, and we do not guarantee exam success. CFA Institute does not endorse, promote, or warrant the accuracy or quality of our products.